The
Competition Commission of India (CCI) in the last three years has pro-actively adjudicated
a large number of matters and has made the industry sit up and take notice of the
huge penalties it has imposed.[1] The role of CCI in the
days to come may have an impact not only on the competitors who are the subject
of an antitrust scrutiny but may well pave the way for changes in the manner of
operations of enterprises, the structures of different ‘markets’ and inevitably influence the market forces in our economy.
Time will determine the role it will play. It will be interesting to see how
the CCI will address several key policy and regulatory issues that it will face
in the days to come. There are numerous issues that it will have to face but a
leader in the pack amongst these issues would be its treatment of the vexed and
often litigious issue of ‘essential facilities’.[2] This issue goes right down
to the theoretical underpinnings of the free market system as it will decisively
pave the way for not only antitrust jurisprudence in our country but also shape
the market system.
International
Application of the Doctrine
The
genesis of this doctrine is normally traced back to the Terminal Railroad Association case[3], a US Supreme Court
decision rendered a century ago in 1912.[4] The Terminal Railroad Association case concerned a fact situation
wherein a terminal railroad association obtained control of every means of
railroad access to St. Louis and the Court had to consider whether such a
system by which every terminal railroad facility was controlled by the
association and thereby controlled the movement of traffic into and out of St
Louis would be a combination in restraint of trade.[5] In addressing this
question, the Court found that the geographical and topographical situation was
such that it was impossible for any
railroad to pass through or even enter St. Louis without using the facilities
controlled by the terminal company.[6] Furthermore, it was
observed by the Court that the facilities could only be used by the members of
the Association and non-members could only be admitted upon a unanimous consent
of all the existing members.[7] It would also be relevant
to note that the Supreme Court had identified that the terminal companies were
of the greatest public utility[8] and in the extraordinary
physical and topographical conditions that existed unless the terminal company was
to operate as an impartial agent of all, interstate trade and commerce would be
significantly impeded.[9] Finally, the Court found
that the practices of terminal company were operating to the disadvantage of
commerce that had to cross the river at St. Louis.[10] In this background the
Court observed that it would be best to provide non-discriminatory access to
the terminal facilities to non-members as well.[11] An analysis of the
judgment would reveal that the Supreme Court never specifically identified the
‘essential facilities doctrine’ but
however, felt that in the extraordinary physical and topographical conditions
as it was practically impossible to access St Louis and as the facilities were
of greatest public utility to ensure freedom of commerce it was necessary that
the non-members should be allowed to the combined ownership of the facilities
on just and reasonable terms. It should also be borne in mind that this was the
situation at the beginning of the last century and the economic and social
conditions were vastly different at that particular point of time.
The
next important case on the aspect of essential facilities is the Associated Press case[12]. The case revolved around
the admission policy in the Associated Press (AP), an organisation consisting
of the membership of 1200 newspapers. The By Laws of the Associated Press mandated
that news shall not be sold to non-AP members. Therefore, to have access to the
news it was necessary to become members and restrictions (in the form of
additional conditions) were imposed on the competitors of the members of the
Association from gaining admission to AP.[13] The majority opinion
rendered by Justice Black opined that the action was contrary to the provisions
of competition and the effect of the action was to limit the opportunity of
newspapers to enter new cities and the effect was to destruct competition and
block new entrants into the market.[14] The Supreme Court held
that by the combinations the members had surrendered completely to the
association and the restraint was designed in the interest of preventing
competition.[15]
However, Justice Frankfurter who joined in the majority (who provided indications of the essential facilities doctrine) observed that the AP
unlike other commercial entities that worked for profit had a relation to
public interest in dissemination of information and further turned down the
objection that this would turn AP into a public utility (as opposed to a
private club) because such a categorization should not come in the way of
access to news and information.[16]
Finally,
in the year 2004, the US Supreme Court in the case of Verizon Communications Inc v. Law
Offices of Curtis v Trinko LLP[17] held that the Supreme Court has never recognised the essential
facilities doctrine.[18] The challenge under the
Trinko Judgment was the denial to share network mandated under the
Telecommunications Act, 1996 to competitors. Under the Telecommunications Act
of 1996 local exchange carriers were mandated to provide access to their
networks to competitors or new entrants and it was argued that the Verizon was
providing access to its network on a discriminatory manner to the detriment of
the competitors and was therefore acting contrary to the provisions of the Sherman
Act. In this context the Court ruled that
for an attempt to monopolise it is necessary to show in addition to the
possession of monopoly power in the relevant market[19], “the willful acquisition
or maintenance of that power as
distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic
accident.[20]
The Court further observed that directing / compelling firms to share their
infrastructure would not be in line with the underlying purpose of competition
law as it may lessen the incentive for enterprises to invest in economically
beneficial facilities. Furthermore, it will also require the Court to act as
the central planners for the industry[21] and could facilitate
collusion among the parties[22] and thereby impeding the
objective of the Sherman Act. The Court also noted that because of these
uncertain virtues, very cautiously and only under very limited exceptional circumstances
will sharing be mandated. The Court noted that the case did not fall within
these exceptions.[23] In this context the Court
noted that even under the essential facilities doctrine (which the Supreme
Court did not feel the need to recognise) the challenge will not succeed. The
Court held that the in-dispensable requirement for invoking the doctrine is the
unavailability of access to the
“essential facilities” and where access exists, the doctrine serves no
purpose. Specifically in this case the Court held that since the
Telecommunications Act of 1996 provides for sharing, there was access to
facility. Therefore, in effect the Supreme Court did not even feel the need to
recognise the doctrine and provided a very narrow compass for its application
even in the event if it were to apply. The position of essential facilities in
the European Community jurisprudence is different and is discussed below.
The
concept of mandating access to facilities in Europe originated from leveraging
and the special status assigned to dominant undertakings under Article
82. The first case where the reference to essential facility was used was the
case of Sealink/B&I Holyhead: Interim
Measures.[24]
In this case Sealink owned as well as ran ferries in the Holyhead Port. B&I
was also running ferries from this port and challenged the change in the time
table proposed by Sealink as it would adversely disrupt the operations of
B&I. In this regard, the Commission adopted interim measure and observed
that Article 82[25]
would be infringed if a dominant undertaking which both owns and uses an
essential facility ( defined as a
facility without access to which competitors cannot provide services to their
customers) and refuses competitors access to that facility or grants access
to competitors only on terms less favourable than it gives its own services.[26] The Commission observed
that the dominant undertaking should not leverage its dominant position in one
market to protect its position in another market (as in the present case
operating harbours and running ferries) and where the competitor is already
subject to certain level of disruption by the dominant undertaking there is a duty on the dominant undertaking not to take any action which will
result in further disruption.[27] The Commission observed finally
that a competitive disadvantage could not be imposed by the dominant
undertaking by altering its own schedule.
Next
is the landmark judgment of Magill[28]
wherein the TV broadcasters obtained an injunction against Magill TV Guide Ltd
from publishing comprehensive TV weekly guides. The actions of the TV
broadcasters in refusing to grant licenses for weekly TV listings was
successfully challenged by Magill as an abuse of a dominant position. The
European Court of Justice held that the TV broadcasters were the only sources of the basic information
(copyrighted TV guide) which was indispensable for the
emergence of the new product (viz. weekly TV Guide) for which there was
consumer demand. Furthermore, the Court found that there was no substitute for
the said product and there was no justification for the refusal by the TV
broadcasters and by doing so they were reserving the entire secondary market of
weekly TV guides to themselves. Therefore, in directing the action of the
broadcasters to be abusive the Court observed specifically that the information
was indispensible and the only source
and which also had significant consumer demand and thereby provided a parameter
for the ‘essentiality’ of the essential facilities. Furthermore, it will be
significant to note that the Court relied upon the earlier cases on refusal to
deal relating to downstream markets[29] to hold that the
competition in the downstream market for weekly TV Guides was reserved to
themselves. Therefore, in this way they also identified the circumstance under
which the doctrine had to be applied.
The
next important judgment was the Oscar
Bronner case[30] decided once
again by the ECJ. The challenge in this case pertains to the denial by
Mediaprint to allow Oscar Bronner to be part of its home delivery system for distribution
of newspapers. It was argued that access to the nationwide system for
distribution was essential for sale of its newspaper.[31] The Court observed that
the refusal to supply raw materials or services, which were indispensible to carry on the rival’s business, to an
undertaking competing with the dominant undertaking was previously held abusive
by the ECJ in the context where the conduct was likely to eliminate all
competition on that part of the undertaking. Further referring to the Magill
Case, the Court observed that even if that test were to be applied to the case
at hand other modes for distributing newspaper even though less advantageous
existed and was used by other newspaper publishers[32] and there were no
technical, legal or economic obstacle for the newspaper publishers to develop
their own nationwide home delivery scheme for distributing newspapers.[33] Finally the Court held
that to demonstrate that developing a potential alternative
distribution system was not realistic or not economically viable and therefore
the system was indispensible, it was necessary to demonstrate that it is not
economically viable to create a second home-delivery scheme for the
distribution of daily newspapers with a circulation comparable to that of the
daily newspapers distributed by the existing scheme[34] as opposed to saying that
it was not economically viable as a result of the small circulation of the
newspapers to be circulated.[35] In this background, it
was held that the refusal by the dominant undertaking to access to its
distribution / home delivery system was not an abuse of a dominant position.
Finally,
we shall discuss the Court of First Instance (CFI) Judgment in the Microsoft case[36],
wherein the case related to the non-disclosure by Microsoft of interoperable
information. While addressing the indispensability requirement or the degree of
interoperability that was required the Court held that the standard that has to
be used is with reference to what is necessary to remain viably on the market.[37] The CFI justified this on
the interpretation that Article 82 deals with
conduct that hinder the maintenance of effective competition on the market
and that furthermore the jurisprudence of ECJ imposed a special responsibility on the dominant undertakings not to impair
genuine undistorted competition in the market.[38] The CFI then found that
the finding of the Commission that the ‘interoperability with the client PC
operating system is of significant competitive importance in the market for
work group server operating systems’ was correct and Microsoft could not prove
otherwise.[39]
Microsoft also argued that the test applied by the Commission was incorrect[40] in the light of the
earlier cases pertaining to abuse of dominance where the refusal should have
been likely to eliminate all competition or in other words there is a high
probability that the conduct will have such a result.[41] The CFI held that this
was only a matter of terminology[42] and that the objective of
Article 82 would not be served if the Commission were to wait till there is no
competition in the market. Furthermore, the CFI held that the standard that
needs to be demonstrated is the refusal is likely to eliminate ‘all effective
competition’ on the market.[43] Finally the Court
observed that the practice of not granting interoperable information would
amount to an abuse of a dominant position. It will be relevant to observe that
the Microsoft judgment has to be viewed in the light of the specific market
situation it dealt with (viz. software and high technology market which was
characterised by network effects) and what would be the effect of the actions of
Microsoft in future on such a market where it is necessary to have
interoperable information.
Applicability of the
Doctrine in India
The
political, economic and social milieu of India has been very distinct from the
western countries and this remains a very important parameter when a doctrine that
has its genesis in the western world has to be applied in our context. Since
independence in 1947 till the early 1990s India remained under the License Raj and
the industries were regulated and tied down by various government policies. The
industries could develop only in accordance with the dictates of the Government
and their development and regulation was significantly kept under control by New
Delhi. Furthermore, the Government also gave special impetus to Public Sector
Enterprises to grow and serve the dual role of free enterprise and welfare
state. During this time the Government through the Public Sector Enterprises has
developed infrastructure and various facilities. Post the liberalisation era,
the industries were de-regulated and private participation and investment
has vastly increased. However, a natural distortion existed in the level
playing field as the Public Sector Enterprises had access to their own
resources and which were not immediately available to the new private entrants.
It will also be worthwhile to mention that since the early days of
privatisation various private players have also made significant investments
into various facilities. At this juncture, various entities operating or
looking to enter into a market may want to have access to the various facilities and infrastructures
developed by PSUs and various private enterprises who had
invested in infrastructure. The question would be whether
the essential facilities doctrine should be applicable in India? This is an
interesting question that CCI will face.
The
issues will range from the applicability of the doctrine itself in the first
case. Section 4 of the Competition Act provides that limiting markets, practices
resulting in denial of market access and leverage to protect another market are
specific instances of abuse of dominant position. Whether essential facilities
will be covered under any of these categories will be at the forefront of the applicability of the doctrine in India. The US
Supreme Court has already felt the need not to recognise the doctrine. The US
SC in Verizon has also identified that there are uncertain virtues in forced
sharing.[44]
Therefore, the principle question would be whether the doctrine should actually
be applied in India. Furthermore, the Courts in India have time and again cautioned
from applying principles that have been developed outside India to be applied
in the Indian context. Should a doctrine actually originating outside India be applied in India and that
too which has not been recognised in US (seen as a leader in antitrust jurisprudence).
Furthermore, regard should be had to the fact that the courts in Europe have applied
the essential facilities doctrine in the background of the Special
Responsibility of the Dominant Undertaking (a concept that is alien to Indian
jurisprudence) and in the light of teleological interpretation adopted to protect the
common market in Europe and the overall purpose of integration of Europe.
If at all the doctrine should be applied under what circumstances
should the doctrine be applied will be the next question – should the infrastructure be a public utility
or be of great public importance for the development of commerce and trade in
India. Furthermore, the more important question would be on the determination of 'essentiality'. Should the facility be
indispensable (impracticable to replicate as observed in Terminal Railroad or
facility without which services cannot be provided as observed in Sealink or indispensable
to provide a product as mentioned in the Magill case) or should it be viable for
competition (as observed by CFI in the Microsoft judgment). This would be a key
factor and it is necessary before arriving at such a decision to balance the
interest of the innovators and the investors of infrastructure else free riders
may take undue advantage. Last but not the least would be to check after
determining ‘essentiality’ when can the doctrine be applied – is it in a
situation when the conduct is likely to eliminate all competition (Magill or
Oscar Bronner) or it is likely to eliminate all effective competition in the
market (as in Microsoft Judgment). In addition, crucial to the determination of this issue would be the determination of the relevant market and whether the features of essentiality and applicability of other conditions are applicable in that particular relevant market. A key ingredient for determining the abuse of dominant position under Section 4 is the relevant market. Economic tools and data will have to be clearly adduced to suggest in determining the relevant market and further it has to be used in determining the viability or essentiality of a facility.
It
will also not be out of place to mention that the Indian legislators / policy
makers too have, whenever felt necessary mandated access to
information / resources like in the case of the interconnection agreements for
telecom and open access in the case of the electricity distribution. Therefore,
the CCI in this circumstance when it seeks to apply the essential facilities
doctrine would not only be donning the role of adjudging the illegal practices
on the market but may also have to wear the cap of a policy maker. It will be
interesting to see how the CCI applies this doctrine and instead of applying
the doctrine in the form developed in the western jurisdictions, the Indian
economic, social and market conditions should be taken into consideration while
adjudging upon the access to ‘essential
facilities’ for this is where the destiny of the essential infrastructure in
India lies.
[1] Notably among these being the
DLF case and the recent cement cartelisation case
[2] In an
ongoing CCI investigation the issue of access to essential facilities has
already been raised
[3] 224 US 383
[4] Although the case by itself does
not refer to the essential facilities doctrine
[5] Supra note 3 at Pg 394
[6] Id at Pg 397
[7] Id at
399-400
[8] Id at Pg 402
[9] Id at Pg
405; In
this regard, the Supreme Court relied upon the evidence of an expert witness
who had stated that the unification of the terminal systems should be the agent
of every company and that it would be the greatest public utility and of
immeasurable advantage to commerce, state and interstate Id at Pg 405-406
[10] Ibid
[11] Id at Pg 411
[12] 326 US 1
[13] Id at Pg 10-11
[14] Id at Pg
13-14
[15] Id at 19
[16] Id at Pg 29
[17] 540 US 398
[18] Id at Pg 410 and 411 – The Court
observed they have never recognised such a doctrine (as in the essential
facilities doctrine) but also observed that they do not feel the need to
recognise it or to repudiate it in the circumstances of the case at hand.
[19] Comparable
to the dominant position under Section 4 of the Competition Act, 2002
[20] Id at Pg 407
[21] Court observed that in such a
role the Court will have to identify the proper
price, quantity, and other terms of dealing-a role for which they are ill
suited
[22] Id at Pg 407 – 408. Furthermore,
the Court also observed that the virtues of forced sharing are uncertain and it
is difficult to identify and remedy the anticompetitive
[23] Id at Pg 409-410
[24] [1992] 5
CMLR 255
[25] Provision
similar to Section 4 relating to abuse of dominant position
[26] Para 41,
[27] Id at
Para 41 and 42
[28] Cases
C-241/-1/91, P, RTE & ITP v Commission [1995] 4 CMLR 718
[29] Joined Cases 6/73 and 7/73
Commercial Solvents v Commission [1974] ECR 223, Para 25
[30] Case C-7/97, Oscar Bronner GmbH
& Co KG v Mediaprint [1999] 4 CMLR 112
[31] Id at Para 37
[32] Id at
Para 43
[33] Id at Para 44
[34] Id at
Para 46
[35] Id at
Para 45
[36] Case T-201/04, Microsoft v
Commission [2007] ECR II-2601
[37] Id at Para 229
[38] Ibid
[39] Id at
Para 381
[40] The Commission used the test
whether the refusal gave risk of elimination of competition
[41] Id at
Para 560
[42] Id at
Para 561
[43] Id at Para 563
[44] Noted
Antitrust Commentator Philip
Areeda has commented in his famous article that no case provides a consistent
rationale for essential facilities or explores the social costs and benefit of
requiring a creator to share with a rival, See his article Essential Facilities: An Epithet in need of limiting Principles, 58
Antitrust LJ 841
No comments:
Post a Comment